Friday, December 30, 2022

Last mailbag of the year


www.slowboring.com
Last mailbag of the year
Matthew Yglesias
28 - 35 minutes

Not a lot of news of any kind in the final week of the year, but some upbeat things I learned this week:

Solar output in 2021 exceeded the IPCC’s most optimistic forecast for 2030. DC is set to close the year with murders and carjackings both down about ten percent. After declining during the worst of the pandemic, the American population is growing again. There are large positive health effects of closing coal-fired power plants, even if the replacement is natural gas.

On to the questions and Happy New Year!

Lost Future: Why does it seem like immigrants assimilate much more smoothly in the US than in Europe?

The obvious reason is that the United States, like Canada and Australia and a few other settler societies, has a longstanding self-conception as a “nation of immigrants,” which means that even people who are very skeptical of immigration on a policy level tend to have a clear story about why “the good ones” are fine. We’re a country whose anti-immigrant populist leader was married to a Slovenian-born woman who maybe did some paid work that was inconsistent with her original visa status.

This has a productive symbiosis with the fact that the United States is a much more patriotic country than most of western Europe. So the official ideology of the United States is that immigrants are welcome here, but then you are asked to do something that is both very specific and also very doable in order to be accepted as an American and that’s be patriotic. Wave a flag. Respect the troops. Stand for the national anthem. We have this civic religion of founding fathers who, like any great set of myths, can have their lives told and retold again for new generations with interpretations that suit the times.

On the other side, I think Europeans exacerbate their disadvantages in two ways.

One is that a large share of immigrants to many European countries come specifically from former colonies. There are understandable historical reasons for that, but it creates a tougher bar for new residents and their family to adopt a “rah rah” patriotic spirit. The other is that lots of European countries have formally recognized national minority populations and official policy structures in place to recognize and support the established minority community. There’s a special school system for the Swedish-speaking minority in Finland, and they have their own political party. Belgian politics is structured around separate Francophone and Flemish institutions. Corsica, Catalonia, and lots of other regions special status. The unintended consequence of having these separate formal identities is that it creates a presumption of an ethnic basis of citizenship, and that equality means a kind of separateness.

The shadow cast by all these dimensions is that, of course, the worst-off groups in the United States are the groups descended from enslaved people or from the conquered indigenous population — the exceptions to the “nation of immigrants” narrative.

Last but by no means least, it’s worth saying that assimilation in the American context means something that Europeans might find a bit odd. Last spring I was talking to an Irish guy — as in actually born and raised in Ireland — who was surprised by how enthusiastic Joe Biden was about the official St Patrick’s Day celebration in the United States. After all, it’s Biden’s great-great-grandparents who emigrated from Ireland. But there’s a very well-established tradition in the United States of families hanging on to very vague and distant ethnic roots without that being seen as in tension with them being fully American. And that ties back into American patriotism. We are really asking people to affirm certain things about American civic culture, not to give up on attachments to the old country.

Benjamin, J: Can Congress claw back more power from the executive, and if it can what is the most likely scenario for it to do so?

The only impediment to “congress” clawing back power “from the executive” is that congress would need to want to claw back power from the executive.

If there were anything remotely resembling a bipartisan consensus in congress that it would be good for this to happen, the obstacles to it happening would be trivial. But congress would need to actually want it to happen, which they mostly don’t. Members of congress need to balance policy goals and partisan goals against personal goals like winning re-election, but nobody sacrifices all of those goals together for the sake of bolstering the institutional power of congress.

One thing I’d say about this, though, is that I think congressional abdication of governing authority has in practice empowered the judicial branch. The American state wouldn’t work at all unless lots of practical decision-making was delegated to the executive branch. But an active and efficient legislature could be constantly changing the scope and terms of executive delegation if it felt that delegated autorities were being misused or abused. In practice, that never happens. Instead of answering a question like “does congress want the president to have the leeway to do X?” as a practical question in which the answer is “if they don’t like it they will pass a law saying so,” we just assume that basically no laws on any subject will ever pass congress. So it becomes an abstract question where federal appellate judges make up answers, and they and their interns wield vast power in a way that I don’t think is in keeping with the intended spirit of Madisonian government.

Federowski: You’ve said that you’ve avoided discussing AI risk because you haven’t been presented with actionable and concrete proposals that policymakers/political actors should adopt that maybe are neglected. I think the same could be said of many different topics. But isn’t this precisely one reason to highlight such issues even more? Maybe more people should be thinking about solutions, arguably a lot more people than currently are, and you could help move the needle in that direction — say, in the same way you’ve directed people to think twice about working for Facebook.

I sort of agree with this. But the thing to keep in mind is I also want to publish articles that are good, and that to an extent limits me to topics where I have good ideas for articles.

But I will say that I liked this Katja Grace post arguing that the AI safety community should become more open to the idea of deliberately slowing AI development. I think it’s obvious that OpenAI is incredibly proud of the work that went into ChatGPT rather than ashamed that they built a bunch of safety features into it that either don’t work or else are easily evaded. It’s easy to understand where that pride comes from — their work is very impressive — but it also speaks to the culture of the software industry. In software it’s become normal practice over a span of decades to release buggy products and try to fix them later. Commercial aviation doesn’t work like that. In commercial aviation, the planes are really, really not supposed to crash. When it turned out the Boeing 737 Max had a design flaw that caused the plane to crash in certain circumstances, that was a big embarassing fuckup, not a moment for bragging about how all things considered the 737 Max was a pretty impressive engineering feat.

This is a regulatory fact, but it’s also part of the culture of commercial aviation. The guys who work at Boom Supersonic don’t do a lot of public bragging about “move fast and break things.” This absolutely slows down the pace at which commercial aviation capabilities increase. But it also ensures that planes are extremely safe. And even though there are intense international rivalries in aviation, and even though international coordination is imperfect, there really is a lot of international coordination on safety.

Charles Target: Not a question really, more a request for guidance and a long take on something I'd love to understand: What does the shift to a service economy mean for the inflation-wage-productivity nexus? With goods, prices can often fall while wages and productivity rise. Prosperity! But with services? Seems much harder. E.g. if food service workers are to make real wage gains, do the rest of us have to get used to eating fewer, more expensive meals? (Geneva minimum wage $25/hour: Price of Swiss Big Mac $13.50).

In her autobiography, Agatha Christie writes about living in London in 1919 with her husband. They had a live-in maid and were expecting their first child so they started looking to hire a nanny. She writes decades later: “Looking back, it seems to me extraordinary that we should have contemplated having both a nurse and a servant. But they were considered essentials of life in those days, and were the last things we would have thought of dispensing with. To have committed the extravagance of a car, for instance, would never have entered our minds. Only the rich had cars.”

So, yes, what happens over time is that labor-intensive services get more expensive. Today, of course, more people own cars than pay for regular housecleaning, but more to the point, the broad mass of affluent people hire someone to clean once a week — a full-time live-in servant would be a wild extravagance.

The good news is that unlike Christie, we have things like dishwashers and laundry machines to lighten the load.

In terms of restaurants, I think the key thing is that traditionally there’s been a sense that fast food chains mean bad food. But the big recent trend in dining has been “fast casual” restaurants: Shake Shack and Chipotle rather than McDonalds and Taco Bell. The idea here is that instead of making the cheapest, fastest meal possible, you’re trying to make a pretty good meal in the least labor-intensive way possible. Eventually, I think upmarket counter service will displace broader and broader swathes of the restaurant market, leaving the full-service experience for true fine dining establishments where the price is so high that the cost of paying a server to bring you your food is trivial.

Sravan Bhamidipati: Apparently news headlines are often not written by the writer of the article. Why does this practice exist? How common is this? Why do journalists, who bear the brunt of the criticism about headlines, not push back? Curious how the incentives are all aligned towards preserving this when every reader and writer seems to agree it is bad.

Traditionally this has to do with how a newspaper is designed and assembled. The question of which stories go where in the newspaper is a high-level editorial decision, and not up to the reporters or even the assigning editors. And then what headline should go on a piece is in part a downstream function of where the headline is running physically. Things like sub-heads are then in part page layout elements designed to make the article fit. So in this context, headline-writing is part of that page-assembly process, not part of writing the article.

When we launched Vox, though, we created an editorial process so that the author of the piece and the editor who worked on it decided on the headline.

Joel Kohn: I saw Glass Onion yesterday and didn’t like it. My main issue is that the movie seems to be built around taking down “characters” who are pretty obvious archetypes for real world people the director doesn’t like. It fells like this has become a pattern in entertainment. Creators feel like they have to make political statements with their art at the expense of its quality. Don’t Look Up, The Last Jedi, that terrible episode of The Simpsons with Hugh Jackman and Robert Reich all come to mind.

Am I just a grumpy old man or has our current politics made entertainment worse?

I think you are just a grumpy old man. That Simpson’s episode and Don’t Look Up aren’t very good, but that’s because they’re not good. I thought The Last Jedi had some interesting ideas but fundamentally doesn’t work because the story is disorganized and the whole three-movie arc doesn’t make sense.

But “Glass Onion” was fun! I think both the people who are praising its politics and the people annoyed by its politics are seeing more politics in the movie than are really there. I would just say that if you haven’t seen the movie yet but you are worried you might be annoyed by leftist politics, just close your eyes and repeat to yourself three times “this is a right-wing movie about Sam Bankman-Fried not a left-wing movie about Elon Musk” before you fire it up and you’ll be fine.

EP: What's your take on the Twitter Files story - real crisis for free expression or manufactured tempest in a teapot?

It’s neither of those things. I think that we knew, broadly speaking, that Twitter content moderation was not going very well. The Twitter Files stories have fleshed that picture out but not revolutionized my understanding of what was going on. The one that moved my views the most was Lee Fang’s one about Twitter working with the Pentagon to assist with US information operations abroad, but that’s also been the least-hyped story because it doesn’t play into right-wing ax-grinding about Twitter.

The thing that really makes these stories not so interesting is that Elon Musk already bought Twitter, and it was clear from the beginning that his plan was to stop doing content moderation with a progressive thumb on the scales and instead do content moderation with a conservative thumb on the scales. And I think that’s fine. It’s his company, he can do what he wants. But literally, he can do whatever he wants. He doesn’t need to “prove” that the prior policies were bad in order to change them. If he wants to deliberately make the content moderation policies worse, he can do that. It’s his company!

Bennie: There has been a lot of Monday morning quarterbacking over the 80s-90s decisions to open trade with China. While some of the specifics could have been handled better, wasn’t it still the right thing to do When the world’s most populous nation appears to be making a big move from communism to capitalism, do you work with them or tell them to get lost?

I don’t think “get lost, we’re refusing to trade with you” would have been a good idea. But I also wouldn’t downplay the extent of the failures here.

The key thing on the domestic front is that Permanent Normal Trade Relations only led to tiny changes in actual US tariffs on Chinese imports. Because those tariff changes were so small, the American officials who crafted the policy thought the impact of import volumes would be pretty small. This was really wrong and the permanent part of PNTR turned out to be a huge deal in terms of driving supply-chains and investment decisions. This was a big analytical error on the part of Clinton-era proponents of PNTR. The China shock that unfolded after they left office was both larger and faster than they’d anticipated, meaning the economic transition for affected areas (especially in the Midwest) was bigger and worse than they anticipated and also the opening to China ended up substantially undermining their prior policy of doing NAFTA to promote Mexican economic development.

If they’d understood the situation properly, they still would have done the opening-up (it was on net beneficial to Americans) but they would have designed the process to unfold more slowly so there was more time for reallocation to take place.

But the other big mistake was that George W. Bush reacted to the events of 9/11 with not just specific anti-terrorism moves, but by conceptually framing the United States as engaged in a generational ideological struggle comparable to World War II or the Cold War. This greatly delayed recognition of the need to think of competition with China as a relevant frame for analyzing big decisions. When I went to China in 2008 on a propaganda tour for journalists, PRC officials were quite open about the idea that the post-9/11 orientation of American policy was a huge win for them, so I’m sure American officials were aware of this as well. And Barack Obama sort of tried to change this with his “pivot to Asia,” but that was much more like a “gradual turning of a huge slow boat toward Asia.” Eventually under Trump and Biden we got there, but the whole process started 10 years too late.

Bob: We are approaching the most consequential and significant election in our lives. Of course I am referring to the 2023 Kentucky gubernatorial election. What are your thoughts and predictions for the race?

As you know, I’m a big Medicaid expansion guy and thus a leading member of the Beshear Hive. Kentucky is a very conservative state, so I wouldn’t count Republicans out, especially with Joe Biden in the White House. But it’s worth noting that Beshear was very popular the last time polling was done in October and incumbent governors in general did well in 2022, so I think he’ll probably get re-elected. Republicans don’t even have a nominee yet so we don’t know how crazy they’ll go. But it’s Kentucky where even really nutty far-rightists like Rand Paul can win.

Scott: As someone who believes that proportional representation is the best solution to gerrymandering, what do you think the best path is to getting PR adopted by either a state legislature or the House of Representatives? Are there organizations out there working on this? All I’ve seen is FairVote, but it seems like they’ve switched their focus to IRV.

I wouldn’t say FairVote has switched their focus, exactly. The big proximate problem with proportional representation is the common belief that a provision of the Voting Rights Act constrains states’ ability to adopt PR. The concern was that a majority-white state might say “we’re going to have six at-large members rather than six members, each of whom represent one-sixth of the state” in order to get out of needing to draw majority-Black districts, so they curtailed states’ ability to rely on at-large districts. Of course if you elected six at-large members in a proportional way, there would be no dilution of Black voting power at all. On the contrary, you’d have guaranteed representation without needing to resort to funny-looking districts. But people say the VRA is written in such a way as to not draw that distinction.

It’s never been clear to me if that interpretation is actually what courts would run with. But the proximate step forward would be legislation clarifying that proportional representation is permissible.

Carl Johnson: Will summer homes become more popular in the era of climate change and remote work? Winter homes?

My dad has had a summer house my whole life, and something I always struggle a little to explain is that he wasn’t really quite as rich as “owns a summer house” implies — he’s just been a remote worker with a flexible schedule all along. One big problem with buying a summer house is that it’s expensive. But another problem is that it seems wasteful: there’s this big home and you can only use it for a tiny fraction of the year. But it was much less wasteful for my dad than it was for my friends’ parents who were lawyers or worked in finance, because he could (and still does) spend very long summers in Maine working remotely. Now, thanks to remote work, a larger fraction of affluent people are going to decide that it makes sense to get a vacation house near seasonal leisure amenities.

This is part of a larger theme I’ve been trying to develop, which is that we need to understand remote work as spurring a dramatic increase in demand for housing. Over time that’s either going to mean scarcity that really hurts the poor, or else we adopt lots of YIMBY measures and the amount of square feet per person will go up a lot — in part because of home offices, but also because of increased consumption of seasonal housing. Some of that will be rich people buying second or third homes, but a lot of it will probably be through the Airbnb/Vrbo market.

Matt: If you could make one change to the US healthcare system, what would it be?

The idea of “one change” seems misleading because I think you could write down “everyone should get comprehensive government-provided health insurance” and say that’s one change.

So I’m going to offer a tedious technical change that I nonetheless think is important: I would make it possible for people who are on Medicaid to purchase supplemental insurance plans. Right now, you either get Medicaid or you don’t. If you’re eligible for Medicaid but also for a job-based plan that offers better benefits than Medicaid, you either need to take Medicaid for free or else pay the full price for the job-based plan. The situation with Medicare is different. With Medicare, you can (and many people do) buy a “Medigap” plan to supplement Medicare coverage. This is also how health insurance works in Australia and Singapore where everyone gets a very bare bones plan from the government and then most people supplement that with private insurance.

Right now the non-supplementability of Medicaid isn’t a huge deal in practice because Medicaid beneficiaries are mostly very low-income. But the non-supplementability of Medicaid makes expanding Medicaid eligibility further up the economic ladder dicier than it should be, and makes it hard for states to experiment with creative ideas like a “Medicaid buy-in” plan.

Amir Sagiv: I’ve been listening to “Bad Takes” and generally speaking love it. I was wondering, though, given your recent commentary on Twitter with its spiralling-downward dynamics, whether you think the format of taking people’s bad take as the starting point somewhat… bad? By which I don’t mean not entertaining, or not useful, but somehow psychologically draining for you personally; continuation of Twitter by other means. The same way that watching Fox or OAN all day long can be.

I’m glad you like it (subscribe here!) but to your point, I would say that I actually find it therapeutic.

Part of what I am trying to do is spend less of my Twitter time dwelling on negativity and other people being wrong about stuff. But it’s still the case that negativity is compelling and other people being wrong about stuff is annoying. In the podcast format, I think it’s possible to leverage that annoyance to create content that’s actually somewhat enlightening about broader issues.

John: How much of Boston’s (and the surrounding area’s) high housing prices are attributable to the smallness of the city’s geographically? in other words, what if boston proper was boston plus suffolk county, cambridge, somerville, quincy, brookline, medford, malden etc instead of a small big city surrounded by smaller cities?

I have 2 thoughts on why small municipal borders may be a culprit: the costs associated with more people living in everett, for example, aren’t balanced out for everett by more jobs and companies to tax in cambridge; the search for high quality schools adds to housing prices in a town like arlington but this wouldn’t be as big a factor if education was leveled across the region.

William Fischel, who’s like the godfather of land use scholarship, canonically argues that municipal fragmentation in New England leads to unusually NIMBY politics (see his book “Zoning Rules!” for the most up-to-date form of the argument) for basically the reason you outline.

I do think the script may flip on Massachusetts, though, because YIMBY advocacy is increasingly bypassing the municipal landscape altogether and focusing on state legislatures. And here Greater Boston’s very large size relative to Massachusetts becomes an advantage compared to a multi-city state like California, Texas, or Florida or to a state that has big polarization between “the city” and “the rest” (Washington, Oregon, New York). In Massachusetts, I think it really makes intuitive sense to most people and most legislatures to think of housing + transportation policy for the Greater Boston region — which includes commuter rail connections as far as Worcester, Fall River, New Bedford, and Lowell — as state government’s premiere economic development imperative.

Aaron: What are some of the issues with the biggest gaps between your first-choice, optimal policies and second-best, politically feasible alternatives? When writing about such issues, how do you think about the tension/balance between persuading others to adopt your beliefs and preferences regarding your first choice versus using your scarce resources to advocate for suboptimal policies that are nevertheless an improvement on the status quo?

I don’t love the whole first-best / second-best bit. I think the right way to think about policy is to try to understand the status quo and then to try to understand proposals for changing the status quo and then to say as best you can whether the proposal will make things better or not.

Pure first-bestism where you just shit on everything because “the real solution” is some totally different idea is dumb. But I also don’t love the idea of constructing your whole politics around various claims about finding second-best solutions. I just want to try to analyze issues on their merits, to set the status quo as the baseline for comparison, and to help people understand the underlying dynamics.

To make this concrete, one common analysis among economists is that the optimal strategy for climate policy is to price the externality. I basically agree with that, but as everyone agrees, the politics are really hard. So some people talked themselves into the idea that using random regulatory sticks to block fossil fuel extraction at the source was a good “second-best” policy approach. But the important thing for everyone to understand about this idea is that its apparent greater feasibility hinges entirely on the premise that the policy won’t actually reduce emissions. Because if you did reduce emissions by constraining fossil fuel production, that would have to be because you raised prices substantially. And that’s exactly the thing we decided was politically infeasible. So you end up with activists blocking the Keystone XL pipeline and then angrily denying this did anything to make gasoline more expensive — which I think is probably true, but raises the question of why you did it in the first place.

The Digital Entomologist: How much does executive compensation affect the economy? Is it just bad optics or does it distort functioning of the economy? If we went back to executives making non-obscene amounts of compensation, would American productivity suffer?

This is sort of neither here nor there as to your question, but something I think people don’t know about CEO compensation is that it peaked back in 2000, crashed after the stock market bubble burst, and has stagnated ever since then. You can see the full data on this in the left-wing Economic Policy Institute’s annual report on skyrocketing CEO pay. Sometime a few years back they realized it was no longer skyrocketing, so they switched methodologies from counting compensation in terms of grants of options to counting it in terms of exercise of those options.

CJ: What are some positives of urbanism that could be sold to skeptics that are unrelated to environmental arguments?

I’m against trying to convince people who don’t like cities that they should get into urbanism. It’s unlikely to work and it misframes the relevant policy issues. Imagine if tea were illegal and someone showed up to try to convince me I should support a tea legalization ballot initiative. I might say “I dunno, I don’t like tea — I think most Americans just want to drink coffee.” It would be really dumb for your next move to be to try tell me all about tea, and why tea is good, and the benefits of tea culture in the United Kingdom and whatever else. The policy argument that tea should be legal has nothing to do with convincing people that they as individuals should like tea or arguing about coffee vs tea as preferences.

You should be allowed to build denser housing on land that you own if that’s what you want to do with it because making it illegal for people to do this imposes massive deadweight loss on the economy. That’s the argument. My experience is that it’s really difficult to get people to hear this argument because everyone is constantly on edge and looking out for identity-based arguments where they can have a scrap about the nature of the good life and defend the merits of suburban living. I think it is absolutely crucial to the project of pro-urbanist policymaking to be clear that we are not at all, on any level, trying to persuade even a single person to like cities, enjoy city living, become urbanists, appreciate urbanism, or alter their negative opinion of people who post on the internet about why cities are good. People should be allowed to build what they want — that’s all there is to it.

Dysphemistic Treadmill: Anti-doomerism: What can progressives do to encourage young people to have a positive attitude towards having kids?

This is another area where I don’t think trying to talk people into changing their preferences is going to be very productive. We can make public policy more supportive of parents and children.

But I also think we as a posting community can try to talk people out of the specific claim that climate change means kids born today are likely to grow up with lower living standards than their parents or grandparents. This is a meme that a lot of people seem to sincerely believe, and that I think they believe is grounded in global scientific consensus, but it’s just not what the IPCC reports about climate impact say. It’s of course possible this consensus is mistaken, but my sense is that most doomsayers don’t perceive themselves as outliers who’ve “done their own research,” they think they are faithfully repeating what the IPCC is saying. But what they say is that under current projections of warming, future generations will be worse off than they could have been in a counterfactual version of the future in which less warming takes place. That’s why it’s a good idea to adopt emissions-reducing policies. But living standards are still projected to improve over time.

Thursday, December 29, 2022

Straight White Male: The Lowest Difficulty Setting There Is

Straight White Male: The Lowest Difficulty Setting There Is

Posted on May 15, 2012    Posted by John Scalzi      801 Comments




I’ve been thinking of a way to explain to straight white men how life works for them, without invoking the dreaded word “privilege,” to which they react like vampires being fed a garlic tart at high noon. It’s not that the word “privilege” is incorrect, it’s that it’s not their word. When confronted with “privilege,” they fiddle with the word itself, and haul out the dictionaries and find every possible way to talk about the word but not any of the things the word signifies.


So, the challenge: how to get across the ideas bound up in the word “privilege,” in a way that your average straight white man will get, without freaking out about it?


Being a white guy who likes women, here’s how I would do it:


Dudes. Imagine life here in the US — or indeed, pretty much anywhere in the Western world — is a massive role playing game, like World of Warcraft except appallingly mundane, where most quests involve the acquisition of money, cell phones and donuts, although not always at the same time. Let’s call it The Real World. You have installed The Real World on your computer and are about to start playing, but first you go to the settings tab to bind your keys, fiddle with your defaults, and choose the difficulty setting for the game. Got it?


Okay: In the role playing game known as The Real World, “Straight White Male” is the lowest difficulty setting there is.


This means that the default behaviors for almost all the non-player characters in the game are easier on you than they would be otherwise. The default barriers for completions of quests are lower. Your leveling-up thresholds come more quickly. You automatically gain entry to some parts of the map that others have to work for. The game is easier to play, automatically, and when you need help, by default it’s easier to get.


Now, once you’ve selected the “Straight White Male” difficulty setting, you still have to create a character, and how many points you get to start — and how they are apportioned — will make a difference. Initially the computer will tell you how many points you get and how they are divided up. If you start with 25 points, and your dump stat is wealth, well, then you may be kind of screwed. If you start with 250 points and your dump stat is charisma, well, then you’re probably fine. Be aware the computer makes it difficult to start with more than 30 points; people on higher difficulty settings generally start with even fewer than that.


As the game progresses, your goal is to gain points, apportion them wisely, and level up. If you start with fewer points and fewer of them in critical stat categories, or choose poorly regarding the skills you decide to level up on, then the game will still be difficult for you. But because you’re playing on the “Straight White Male” setting, gaining points and leveling up will still by default be easier, all other things being equal, than for another player using a higher difficulty setting.


Likewise, it’s certainly possible someone playing at a higher difficulty setting is progressing more quickly than you are, because they had more points initially given to them by the computer and/or their highest stats are wealth, intelligence and constitution and/or simply because they play the game better than you do. It doesn’t change the fact you are still playing on the lowest difficulty setting.


You can lose playing on the lowest difficulty setting. The lowest difficulty setting is still the easiest setting to win on. The player who plays on the “Gay Minority Female” setting? Hardcore.


And maybe at this point you say, hey, I like a challenge, I want to change my difficulty setting! Well, here’s the thing: In The Real World, you don’t unlock any rewards or receive any benefit for playing on higher difficulty settings. The game is just harder, and potentially a lot less fun. And you say, okay, but what if I want to replay the game later on a higher difficulty setting, just to see what it’s like? Well, here’s the other thing about The Real World: You only get to play it once. So why make it more difficult than it has to be? Your goal is to win the game, not make it difficult.


Oh, and one other thing. Remember when I said that you could choose your difficulty setting in The Real World? Well, I lied. In fact, the computer chooses the difficulty setting for you. You don’t get a choice; you just get what gets given to you at the start of the game, and then you have to deal with it.


So that’s “Straight White Male” for you in The Real World (and also, in the real world): The lowest difficulty setting there is. All things being equal, and even when they are not, if the computer — or life — assigns you the “Straight White Male” difficulty setting, then brother, you’ve caught a break.


(Update, 11:07 pm: The comment thread hit 800 comments by 11pm and I’ve turned it off, because now I’m going to sleep and tomorrow I travel, and this is the sort of comment thread that needs to be watched closely. I may turn it back on at some later point, but inasmuch as 800 comments already made it slow to load up, don’t necessarily count on it. But after 800 comments, most of what could be said has been, I think.)


(Update 2: Here’s a follow-up article addressing some common questions/comments regarding this piece.)


(Update 3: Some final thoughts here.)


(Update 4, 5/18/22: A ten-year retrospective on the piece is now up.)


A look back at my predictions for 2022

A look back at my predictions for 2022

Matthew Yglesias — Read time: 10 minutes


A look back at my predictions for 2022

Better than last year!


New episode of Bad Takes is out today all about the debate over Louisa May Alcott’s gender identity.


Each December here at Slow Boring, I like to end the year with both a list of probabilistic predictions for the year ahead and a look at the previous December’s predictions. According to the research presented by Philip Tetlock and Dan Gardner in their book “Superforecasters,” practicing predictions in this way can help you get better at predicting things over time.


And I sure hope that’s true because last December, when I did my first-ever look back, my results were terrible and I’ve been dreading this post all year.


The good news is that this year my forecasts did in fact get better — 75 percent of the things I said would happen with 90 percent confidence actually happened, as did 83 percent of the things I had 80 percent confidence in, 70 percent of the things I had 60 percent confidence in, and 50 percent of the things I had 60 percent confidence in.



Remember the goal here is not to get all the predictions right (which would mean only predicting very boring things) but to really nail the calibrations rate. If you say 10 different things have a 70 percent chance of happening, a good calibrations rate would mean you’d see seven of them happen. And since some error is inevitable, what you’d really like to see (and here I failed) is error happening symmetrically in both directions. You can see I suffered here from systematic overconfidence, the columnist’s cardinal sin.


And that’s the main point of the exercise: not that I per se want to become a superforecaster, but that writing these things down with odds attached is a good way of trying to beat back that overconfidence. “If I grab a pair of dice, I probably won’t roll snake eyes five times in a row” and “D.C. probably won’t cancel five days of school for snow this winter” are both predictions I would stand behind, but there’s actually an incredibly large gap between the probabilities associated with these two things. Casual writing tends to elide the difference between “this would be unusual” and “this is spectacularly unlikely.” It also often struggles with efforts to express an idea like “this probably won’t happen, but the odds of it happening aren’t tiny and are rising, and the consequences would be really bad so I’d like you to worry about it.” Attempting to quantify with exact numbers even occasionally is a way of trying to break bad habits.


But to do that, it’s important to examine what went right and what went wrong.


Some predictions that I made about politics

I started off with a troika of predictions about the midterms, all made with high confidence, of which only one came true:


Democrats lose both houses of Congress (90%)


Democrats lose at least two Senate seats (80%)


Democrats lose fewer than six Senate seats (80%)


We’ve discussed the midterms a fair amount in previous columns, but looking back on this, the very early overconfidence about Democratic Senate losses was based on very crude extrapolation from the historical record. The president’s party almost always loses ground in the midterms. The 2022 map, while probably the most friendly Senate map Democrats can get, left them with a bunch of vulnerable seats and zero margin for error. We know that the thermostatic pattern is sometimes disrupted (in 2002, for example), but those disruptions are rare. So I basically reasoned that because thermostatic disruptions are rare, Dems’ odds of holding the Senate were extremely bad.


The right way to think this through would have been to be more specific. If you’d asked me a year ago whether the Supreme Court strike down Roe v. Wade, my forecast would’ve been overwhelming odds of gutting its core protections (à la John Roberts’ proposal in Dobbs) and a greater than 50 percent chance that there would be five votes to rip off the band-aid and formally strike it down. And from there I could have reasoned that there were decent odds that overturning Roe would have a counter-thermostatic effect. I still would have ended up predicting Democrats lose the Senate — Dobbs explains a lot but there was more to it, like good ads from Democrats and bad candidates from the GOP — but I should have been able to reason my way to a more restrained forecast here.


Some better political forecasts:


Nancy Pelosi announces retirement plans (70%)


Stephen Breyer does not retire (60%)


Some version of Build Back Better passes (60%)


Joe Biden is still president (90%)


At least one Biden cabinet-rank official resigns (70%)


Democrats go down at least one governor on net (60%)


Liz Cheney loses primary (80%)


Some version of USICA passes Congress (70%)


I am glad Breyer proved me wrong and only regret not being more confident about Cheney.


One thing I want to point out is that at the time, my “it’s not dead yet” take on Democrats’ reconciliation legislation was moderately contrarian. I think the folks who spent months and months accusing Joe Manchin of acting in bad faith to protect his personal investments in fossil fuels have not publicly reckoned with their own bad forecasts.


I think my incorrect cabinet resignation forecast is fascinating. You don’t get news stories about things that don’t happen, but the level of continuity in the Biden cabinet has been extraordinary. Barack Obama’s cabinet was pretty stable, but by this point in his administration, Peter Orszag, Christina Romer, and Rahm Emanuel had all stepped down from cabinet-rank White House posts, while the only notable Biden change has been in the non-cabinet White House Press Secretary job.


Some predictions about the pandemic

My Covid forecasting was better than my political forecasting. This is perhaps due to good luck, but I think perhaps it’s actually easier to predict things you have a little more emotional and intellectual distance from:


Fewer U.S. Covid deaths in 2022 than in 2021 (80%)


Fewer U.S. Covid deaths in 2022 than in 2020 (80%)


China abandons Covid Zero (70%)


Additional booster shots authorized (80%)


You can start a fight on Twitter right now by going online and tweeting “the pandemic’s over, guys, and has been for a while,” but I think these accurate forecasts are the cash value of what it means for the pandemic to be over. The SARS-CoV-2 virus continues to exist and since it represents an addition to the extant stock of respiratory viruses, it continues to be very bad for the world. Life expectancy at 70 (or older) is just going to be lower going forward than it would have been in a world where the virus didn’t exist. But as a practical matter, the death toll is waning as people enter their twilight years with some built-up immunity from prior infections and booster shots.


The alternative of relying indefinitely on non-pharmaceutical interventions is just not viable, as even Xi Jinping has admitted. But just because “vaxxed and relaxed” is the best we can do in 2022 and 2023 doesn’t make it the best policy — we should be pulling levers to develop better SARS-CoV-2 vaccines (nasal sprays that would block transmission and pan-coronavirus vaccines that wouldn’t be so vulnerable to variants) and stepping-up research on things like virus-killing far-ultraviolet light.


Predictions about the economy

For the second year in a row I underestimated inflation, but less badly this time:


November 2022 year-on-year CPI growth is below 6% (70%)


November 2022 year-on-year CPI growth is above 4% (70%)


The Fed ends up doing more than its currently forecasted three interest rate hikes (60%)


No recession in 2021 (90%)


The unemployment rate stays between 4 and 5% (70%)


Basically, I correctly thought the Fed would hike more aggressively than it was saying, but I incorrectly assumed that would be enough to get us below 6 percent (and I thought unemployment would be higher). I’m going to chalk that up in part to the invasion of Ukraine disrupting world food supplies, but that in turn is just a reminder that bad news can come from any direction and you need to think comprehensively.


I thought it was weird that there was so much recession buzz last winter and felt like that one was kind of a gimme.


There is a lot of negativity bias in people’s processing of the news environment. This leads people to be simultaneously upset about various inflationary conditions like high levels of job openings, labor churn, and understaffing but also panicked about headlines indicating layoffs at various companies. But you have to try to actually integrate these trends in your mind. Nobody wants to get laid off from a cushy white-collar position and need to take a lower-paid retail job, but the fact that all those jobs are open is relevant context for understanding the economic situation of people facing layoffs. It continues to be a historically good time to find a job, and you need to read layoff news in that context.



For broadly similar reasons, I think that right now there is some serious underestimating of the feasibility of securing an economic “soft landing,” but that’s a story for a different piece.


Foreign politics

All of these things happened, except for Orbán losing:


Emmanuel Macron re-elected (60%)


The German traffic light coalition exploits loopholes to get around the constitutional debt brake (70%)


Lula elected president of Brazil (60%)


Viktor Orbán loses power in Hungary (60%)


Sinn Féin becomes the largest party in the Northern Ireland assembly (60%)


On the elections, I was basically just predicting that the polls would hold up, which is more often than not a good bet.


The Germany thing is interesting because I turned out to be right, but the specific sequence of events was different from what I expected. Russia invaded Ukraine and upended the European economy which, among other things, led to the suspension of the constitutional debt brake. But I didn’t think Russia would invade:


Russia does not invade Ukraine (60%)


New U.S. sanctions on Russia (70%)


Saudi Arabia and Israel establish diplomatic relations (60%)


The U.S. and Canada reach an agreement on softwood lumber (70%)


No military conflict between the PRC and Taiwan (90%)


At the time I made these forecasts, Metaculus had the odds of a Russian invasion lower than I did, so I feel okay about getting this one wrong even though it was obviously consequential. At the time, it was clear that Russia was making some kind of threats in the direction of invading, but I don’t think it was clear that an invasion was likely until late January. As I wrote back in early February before the invasion, invading Ukraine was a really bad idea, and I kind of thought Putin would recognize that and pocket some diplomatic concessions instead of wrecking his military.


The sanctions prediction is an example of me actually learning how to get better at predicting stuff. I saw there was a non-trivial chance of an invasion (which would lead to sanctions), but also a decent chance of something short of invasion that still led to sanctioning plus some outside chance of an unrelated dispute, so I put the odds of sanctions higher than the odds of war.


Saudi Arabia and Israel keep getting less and less clandestine about their cooperation, and I thought the Saudis would want to go public about it to gain leverage over the Biden administration, but so far they haven’t. I think maybe the right way to think about it is that a Saudi-Israeli diplomatic breakthrough would play as a “win” for Biden, but the Saudi government doesn’t like Biden and doesn’t want to give him a win.


Meanwhile, it’s just really stupid that this softwood lumber dispute hasn’t been resolved, but sometimes dumb stuff happens.


Uncertainty is annoying

After the midterms, we had the usual round of discourse where some people dunked on Nate Silver for making bad predictions and then other, smarter people countered that 538 does robust calibration checks and they come out well.


But the reason people think these forecasts are bad is that it’s not usual for 538 to say “so-and-so will probably win” and then he loses. But this is, of course, exactly what happens in a well-calibrated forecast. This call in WA-3 in particular got a lot of dunks. But the thing is, there are hundreds of House seats and they’re mostly safe seats — any given cycle will almost certainly have one or two weird “2 in 100” type outcomes. And 30 percent of the people who you say have a 70 percent chance of winning should lose.



The math here isn’t hard, and if you just think of it in terms of gambling it seems totally reasonable — nobody is so good at poker that they win every hand.


But when it comes to big topics of public concern, like who will win the election or what’s happening with the economy, people really want to make and read definitive predictions about what will happen. Even people who say they aren’t interested in predictions tend to implicitly make them, claiming this or that will have catastrophic effects or huge benefits. It’s really hard to admit, especially to yourself, that it’s hard to know what will happen in the future. It’s possible to get better at making predictions, and hopefully I’ll continue to improve. But a big part of doing that well is acknowledging uncertainty rather than insisting on making the correct call all the time. To the best of my knowledge, it’s actually not possible to do that.


Update your profile

Only paid subscribers can comment on this post

Check your email

For your security, we need to re-authenticate you.


Click the link we sent to tka.lee@gmail.com, or click here to sign in.

Wednesday, December 28, 2022

What follows from the idea that new construction raises rents?


www.slowboring.com
What follows from the idea that new construction raises rents?
Matthew Yglesias
13 - 16 minutes

I think the YIMBY movement, reflecting its origins in the very progressive jurisdiction of San Francisco, demonstrates a bit too much interest in arguing with obscure leftist professors and activists and ought to focus more on the concerns and ideas of normal people.

In my dramatic upzoning proposal for D.C., I throw anti-gentrification activists a huge bone (the ability for low-income neighborhoods to opt out), but that’s mostly because it’s a cheap concession to make in D.C. The real policy challenge is developing a proposal that will reassure people who park their car on the street and who worry that more housing will lead to more parking scarcity. “I’m selfishly worried about my parking space” isn’t a great article to submit to the Journal of Obsessive Economics Haters, but I think that in practice, people who are selfishly worried about parking are a bigger obstacle to reform than Marxist geographers, and it’s probably worth paying more attention to them.

But there is one idea in left-NIMBY circles that I think is worth talking about.

The notion that new development actually causes rent increases in nearby areas is a staple of activist rhetoric. I’ve mostly dismissed this argument as opportunistic — it’s a useful thing to pretend to believe if you’re trying to extract certain concessions from developers — but Clayton Nall, Chris Elmendorf, and Stan Oklobdzija did a recent survey where they find that 30 to 40 percent of the national population shares this supply skepticism view. Interestingly, the researchers kicked the tires on people’s more general intuitions about this and found that in other markets, they tend to believe in supply/demand economics. I’ve twice tried to write articles addressing supply skepticism by noting developments in the automobile market, but people aren’t supply skeptics about cars.

So I want to take a different tack today and think about the implications of living in a world where allowing more construction does lead to higher prices.

You’d be saying, in essence, that a new building would generate more demand than supply, which if taken really literally suggests that cities can unleash a kind of perpetual motion machine for economic growth, where supply begets demand which begets supply which begets even more demand. That seems like it’s probably false — but more importantly, if it’s true, that seems like something we’d want to know about! We should take the Supply Skepticism hypothesis seriously, in part because I think it’s probably capturing something correct.

Jerusalem Demsas, writing about Supply Skeptic research, posits that skeptics are essentially confusing cause and effect — construction tends to happen when prices are rising, so it seems like it is causing the price increases:

    Why is housing different? Perhaps because the supply argument seems to defy lived experience. People look around their community and sense that a lot has changed. They see new homes and developments cropping up, even as prices keep rising. This eyewitness account results in people thinking that these new developments either do nothing to alleviate rising prices—or worse, actually cause prices to increase.

Disentangling cause from effect with a mix of opportunistic data-spotting and clever math is something that economics as a profession has gotten very interested in, so a bunch of young economists have tried to look at this empirically and have generally vindicated traditional theory-based supply/demand arguments.

Probably my favorite of these is Kate Pennington’s paper “Does Building New Housing Cause Displacement?: The Supply and Demand Effects of Construction in San Francisco,” which looks at what happens when buildings burn down in a fire and then get rebuilt. She also constructs conceptually separate measures of displacement (when poor people move to poorer zip codes) and gentrification (when rich people move into a neighborhood). She finds “that rents and displacement fall differentially near new market-rate projects, while gentrification increases.” In other words, it’s true that new construction acts as a magnet for affluent newcomers. But it also deflects affluent newcomers from competing for the older nearby housing stock. So you get more gentrification but less displacement — a win-win.

In keeping with the theory that people are confused about causation, I think most people plausibly assume that what Pennington calls gentrification and what she calls displacement are the exact same thing. There is a bias toward zero-sum thinking that holds even though the point of new construction is very literally to create a positive-sum amount of housing.

That said, I am not entirely sure that evidence grounded in this kind of natural experiment fully incorporates the universe of possibilities. I lived briefly in the Columbia Heights neighborhood of D.C. at a time when it offered a pretty low quality of life. The only places to eat were a Subway and a dismal Chinese carry-out, and the local supermarket was a really gross Giant up by Newton Street where Thip Khao1 is now. But one reason that Giant was so gross was that at the time, several big apartment projects were underway directly adjacent to the metro station, and one of them was a brand-new Giant that represented the future of the company's investment in the neighborhood. I had already left the neighborhood by the time the metro-adjacent mixed-use projects were completed. But when they were done, the neighborhood became a much more pleasant spot featuring a nice supermarket, a Target, a bunch of restaurants, a gym, and other appealing amenities. It seems plausible to me that a rule requiring those metro-adjacent parcels to remain vacant would have suppressed local rents, even though it also would have reduced housing supply.

Note that on a technical level, the hypothesis here isn’t that the new housing raised rents — it’s that the new retail amenities on the ground floor of the housing raised rents. All else being equal, I’m sure it’s true that shorter buildings with less housing would have generated more scarcity while taller buildings with more housing would have generated less scarcity. But I think the most salient real estate projects are precisely the kind of transformational mixed-used projects that provide significant amenity benefits.

What’s odd to me about this debate is that “this new market-rate development is bad because it made the neighborhood more appealing and raised demand” seems like conceptual acid that could dissolve all kinds of policy ideas:

    Don’t renovate the crummy playground because a nice new playground will make the neighborhood better, raise demand, and lead to higher rents.

    Don’t recruit and retain excellent teachers at the neighborhood middle school because rising test scores will raise demand for living in the neighborhood and lead to higher rents.

    Don’t solve murders that happen on the neighborhood’s commercial street because solving crimes will deter shooters, make people feel safer, and lead to higher rents. 

Thinking back to my time in Columbia Heights, I noted that the vacant parcels were right by the metro station. At the time I moved there, the station itself was less than four years old. And it’s the station — and the broader opening of the Green Line — that explains why I was there in the first place. Moving to an unfamiliar city with a low-paying job and an affection for urbanism, my roommate and I sought out an affordable place that was near a metro station, which brought us to the 1300 block of Harvard Street. I think it’s unquestionable that the metro station increased demand for living in the neighborhood, and that increased demand helps explain why the big mixed-used projects were happening in the first place.

So is it bad to invest in transit infrastructure projects that raise neighborhood demand?

I would think the opposite. A lot of infrastructure projects don’t work out. But digging the central segment of the Green Line up from the Convention Center to the Shaw station, to U Street, to Columbia Heights, to Petworth, and then connecting it to the suburban stub running to Fort Totten has been a demonstrable success. You see it in the ridership numbers and in the increased demand for living near those stations, demand that was reflected in part in higher prices and in part in new construction. If they’d dug the tunnel and it didn’t increase demand for living near the stations, that would’ve been a sign of failure.

So what are you saying, Matt? You love gentrification and want to see the poor priced out everywhere?

No, but I am saying that our housing affordability solution can’t be to look at cheap neighborhoods and then decide they must be forever consigned to high crime, few parks, bad schools, and low-quality transportation infrastructure. Once you accept that improving quality of life is a legitimate goal for local government, then what you see is that induced demand due to mixed-use projects with nice retail amenities isn’t special. It’s just another example of how making a neighborhood a better place to live is good. But if a neighborhood gets better, demand will rise. The solution is to allow that demand to take the form of new construction rather than just higher prices.

I think it’s important to not be total denialists about the fact that new construction can increase neighborhood desirability because agglomeration benefits are an important part of the case for urbanism.

Traditionally, economics has focused more on agglomeration benefits on the production side — people in related industries benefit from being in proximity to each other. But with more work going remote, I think we will see interest in the consumption amenities side growing. I’m often struck by the fact that New York is more expensive than Boston or D.C. (this is true whether you look at the central city or the whole metro area), even though it has lower wages and incomes. You often see this kind of rent/wage anomaly in places with particularly good or bad weather. Miami and Los Angeles are more expensive than you’d think based on their incomes and Minneapolis is cheaper — that’s because people don’t like the cold.

New York is different. I think people like New York because it’s a bigger city.

Or rather, I think lots of people don’t like big cities at all and wouldn’t want to live in any of these plays. But among the set of people who find the big northeastern cities congenial, New York is seen as the best because it’s biggest and densest and has the most stuff.

D.C.’s population has grown nearly 20 percent since I first moved here, and I would say that not only have a number of specific neighborhoods developed better neighborhood-serving retail amenities as part of that growth, but the city as a whole has become a better place to live. When restaurants sprout up in a neighborhood they are mostly neighborhood-serving restaurants, but a few of them will be “worth a trip” standouts. We have more movie theaters than we used to, one of the only cities that’s true of. There are multiple places you can go to throw an axe with your friends.

Again, this is not a case where “adding housing raised rents” exactly. But I do think it’s true that the influx of real estate investment dollars (both more houses and more commercial real estate) has created more amenities and raised demand for D.C. living. It’s a mistake to deny people’s intuition that development can spur demand, because at the end of the day, we are trying to convince people to be less fearful of investment.

The important thing for everyone to keep in mind is that there must be some kind of limit to this process or else cities could easily generate infinite economic growth and prosperity. Or to put it another way, if induced demand effects were really large and common, then that would only strengthen the case for upzoning because it would imply cities could be creating infinite levels of prosperity.

Suppose we did a broad upzoning all across D.C., and that led to a huge spurt of new construction, and that new construction led to lots of new amenities, and those new amenities created so much new demand that even though the city added residents, marginal prices were higher than ever. Well, thanks to those higher prices, we’d see more construction than ever. That would mean even more new residents and even more amenities and even higher demand. Lather, rinse, and repeat as the city’s population keeps growing, leading to ever-more amenities and ever-higher demand.

It’s true that this growth escalator might generate some downstream problems of higher rent.

But it would also be creating incredibly large amounts of jobs and income, to say nothing of tax revenue that could be used to improve public services or give cash assistance to the poor. Any scenario where investment begets more investment is a scenario where you want the investment.

The fact that we don’t see any city anywhere doing this is good reason to believe that it won’t work because it’s not, as a rule, true that new development leads to higher rents. I think the boring truth is that this is only true in certain very particular cases, but those cases happen to be memorable precisely because a sudden spurt of growth and investment is unusual. But if it does happen, we should see it as good — just as other things that increase demand like better schools or new parks or safer streets or useful infrastructure are good.

Saturday, December 24, 2022

Kardfogu's Guide to Shooty Outlanders


Torchlight II
Store Page
CREATED BY

Kardfogu
Offline
Category: Classes
Languages: English
Posted
Updated
23 May, 2015 @ 7:28am
23 Jun, 2015 @ 1:54pm
20,341 Unique Visitors
1,417 Current Favorites
GUIDE INDEX
Overview
Introduction 
Skillset 
Stats 
Gear 
Tactics 
Hardcore 
Epilogue 
Comments
Torchlight II

Guides
Torchlight II > Guides > Kardfogu's Guides

471 ratings

Kardfogu's Guide to Shooty Outlanders
By Kardfogu
Shooty Outlanders are considered to be the hard-way, but quite the contrary, they are the easiest way to play Outlanders. Shooties have overwhelming damage, unmatched crowd control and they are fun to play!
Shooty Outlanders are actually the Torchlight II versions of the PvE bowazon from Diablo II with much more damage.
Also, boomsticks are cool!

 6
 2


 
 
Award
Favorited
Share
Introduction
Author's Prologue
This is my Boomstick! Hell yeah, I always wanted to say that and now is the time! If you liked the cute lil' Amazon from Diablo II or the elven archer archetype of the countless ARPG games, then you clicked the right link!

What is a Shooty Outlander?
Shooty Outlander is the collection of the overlooked strength builds for Outlanders. All these builds have the common traits as high rate of attacks combined with slighly lower damage and the ability to convey weapon effects.

Pros
Not a glaive-throwing boringlander
Extreme crowd control
Ranged
Powerful
Cons
Hard-to-build

Summary
Well, you won't understand how powerful they are until you try it out, but well-built shooty cripples a boss with the first shot and maintains the blind on it for the duration of the fight. No monster can retaliate to a shooty outlander.

Should I Play it?
Yes...
...if you want to play a good outlander build.
...if you want to fight against extreme odds like modded dungeons with bosses over lvl200 and/or multiple encounters in the same time.
...if you want a boomstick!
...if you play hardcore.
No...
...if you really can't stop playing your glaive spamming boringlander.
Skillset
Main Skills
Shooty Outlanders have quite a lot of options for main skills. Commonly, Shooty Outlanders choose one primary main attack, such as Rapid Fire or Chaos Burst and take Venomous Hail as a secondary attack form.
Rapid Fire 15/15
Rapid Fire is a piercing multi-attack skill and the first one in the outlander's arsenal to deal weapon DPS and potential primary attack. Rapid Fire starts with a low range, but eventually gains enough to become a stable choice endgame.
Rapid Fire conveys all weapon effects.
Common mistake to leave Rapid Fire at 10/15, as the skill gains damage with every point, max it!
Chaos Burst 15/15
Chaos Burst is a piercing, ricocheting multi-attack skill with a high spread, the other potential primary attack for a Shooty Outlander. Chaos Burst deals heavy damage in point-blank range, but it's somewhat lackluster at range.
Chaos Burst conveys all weapon effects.
Chaos Burst is safe to use in melee range of enemies in combination with the blind chance granted by Shotgonne Mastery.
Venomous Hail 15/15
Venomous Hail is an area of effect multiattack skill that requires no line of sight. Venomous Hail is a monster that deals extremely heavy damage, breaks shields instantly and scales with both strength and focus.
Venomous Hail conveys all weapon effects.
Venomous Hail requires only a single cast every time the cooldown resets, to deal damage constantly to a target.
Shotgonne Mastery 15/15
Shotgonne Mastery is the mother of all crowd control, it grants heavy knockback and high chance to stun and blind enemies. If you plan a shotgonne build, you should max this skill obviously. If you plan a pistol build, max this skill and throw away your pistol build asap.
Shotgonne Mastery grants the Shooty Outlander the ability to cripple bosses completely, making this an invaluable must have skill for every decent outlander.

Optional Skills
Optional skills of the Shooty Outlander are quite close to the build, most of them are offensive passives and defensive active skills. All of them help the Shooty Outlander heavily.
Share the Wealth 15/15
Increase in cast speed, attack speed, critical hit chance, everything you ever wanted. While 7% doesn't sound much, it's 7% of hard-to-get bonuses. Charge bonuses shine in bossfights, where they are the most helpful and the easiest to maintain.
Share the Wealth affects nearby players and pets.
Poison Burst 15/15
Poison Burst grants a chance to trigger on kills, on trigger, the target explodes and every enemy takes the damage written in the skills description. On the other hand, it won't help against stronger foes and single target fights are out of question.
Poison Burst requires a skill that conveys weapon effects.
Repulsion Hex 1+/15
Repulsion Hex is the best friend of Rapid Fire. When you add together all the knockback on Shotgonnes and Shotgonne Mastery, it's obvious, nothing gets close in the linear area of Rapid Fire. Repulsion Hex covers the other 330° around the character with knockback, interrupt and the fear status effect.
More points in the skill increase the duration, knockback, the interrupt chance and rate of activation.
Rune Vault 1+/15
Obvious mobility skill with a less obvious use. When you have to move fast, don't even move your cursor just push the button. Attacks in most scenarios come from one direction, if you shoot into that direction you can leap back repeatedly until you're safe again.
Stone Pact 1+/15
Heal over time, and a really heavy one of that, Stone Pact helps you in solo and it is one of the most welcomed skills in multiplayer. If you have spare points, it's never a waste to put some into Stone Pact to increase the heal done.
Stone Pacts affects players and pets standing in it's area of effect.
Bramble Wall 1+/15
Bramble Wall is awesome, he's your best friend to kill when you need someone to sacrifice. Starting with the basics, Bramble Wall is a wall, but it generates a high threat, most enemies will prefer to whack your Bramble Wall instead of you.
You can also attack it to trigger weapon effects or Rune Vault it for healt/mana steal.

Weirdos
Well, yeah, we arrived to the first guide where I have to write about this! While I covered easy-to-use skills in many guides before, this time we've got some serious stuff that is really hard to use effectively.
Shadowshot 15/15
Well, if the released shadowshots had a chance to travel a bit further, they could hit the original target easily, but knockback can help with that. Shadowshot does an extreme amount of damage and can convey effects like there's no tomorrow. Shadowshot is awesome, but unreliable.
Shadowshot is good, but in most cases, it will be outclassed by Chaos Burst and/or Rapid Fire.

Skills to Avoid
Some skills should be avoided, as they doesn't benefit the build in any way or even worse.
Akimbo
Easy maths, endgame any character will have ~1000% bonus damage from strength and focus. In comparison with 1000% from stats, 30% additive bonus damage marginal, that's one reason why Akimbo is awful. After some additional maths, the result will be 2,72% bonus to your damage from Akimbo.
Akimbo gives you a bonus to Execute, which requires autoattacks. Autoattacks are extremely weak, that's another reason why Akimbo is awful.
On top of these, Akimbo requires dualwield pistols, this is the main reason why Akimbo is awful.
Long Range Mastery
Hell, I really hate to hurt this one, but Long Range Mastery is another skill with marginal damage bonus and it's other bonus only affect auto-attacks.
While this one at least works with every ranged weapon, there are better skills to burn the remaining skillpoints.
Dodge Mastery
Endgame ranged weapons require ~500 dexterity, you won't need any point in dodge mastery with that much dodge. On top of that, dodge is unreliable. While dodge can help against the attacks of weaker enemies, the heavy spell attacks used by bosses are impossible to dodge.
Stats
Main Stats
Shooty Outlanders are normally strength builds, but as you can see, there are countless ways to deal elemental damage, especially since the 1.22 update. On top of that, spelltriggers often deal magic damage. Not to mention damage over time builds...
Some useless statistics are ignored, like execute-chance from focus or armor gain from vitality.

Strength
Your goal is to hit the critical hit cap, which comes around ~1000 strength, but each build varies after that.
Damage over time builds on the other hand require no points in strength.
Improves weapon damage and DPS
Shooty Outlanders always deal considerable weapon DPS, increasing this damage is essential for each stat plan.
Improves critical damage
Shooty Outlanders as all outlanders have a naturally high chance to crit, so critical damage bonuses are always welcome. Spelltriggers are magic damage, but their critical damage is affected by strength, only damage over time builds settle with base strength.

Dexterity
Your goal is to hit ~500 dexterity to use endgame weaponry.
Damage over time builds on the other hand require no dexterity, their weapons are usable without meeting the stat requirements.
Improves critical hit chance
Shooty Outlanders require high critical hit chance to make strength a worthwile investment, but that's not the most important reason to have so much dexterity.
Improves dodge chance
Well, one shouldn't really care about dodge, but it won't hurt to have some.
Endgame requirements
Yeah, endgame ranged weapons require 486 dexterity, except for one bow and one crossbow.

Focus
Your goal depends on the build you plan to use. Spelltriggers concentrate on Focus after reaching critical damage cap to reach at least a 1000, while pure weapon DPS builds ignore it completely.
Damage over time builds on the other hand, should have around ~1000 Focus.
Improves magic damage
Shooty Outlanders have no conventional magic damage, but instead, they trigger and convey a lot by weapons! Actually, the most powerful spelltriggers cause magic damage, so they require high focus to increase the damage done by spells like Glacial Spike, Thunder and Meteor.
Damage over time builds deal purely magic damage.
Improves elemental damage
Strange coincidence is that the best spelltrigger weapons often deal elemental damage, thus their damage won't go to waste with Focus investments. Also, weapon DPS spelltriggers also deal elemental damage.

Vitality
Shield is a no, so you need no vitality. If you want to go for defense, forget shields, use a shotgonne instead!
Improves block chance
Well, we really don't care about block chance if we can cripple everything with blind, do we?
Gear
Gearing
Generally, Shooty Outlanders can go with a shotgonne, dualwield, pistol+shield. Shotgonnes are obviously the best mix of offense and defense, outclassing shield builds completely. Dualwield may work, but it rarely offers enough increase in damage to make up for losing the blind chance from shotgonnes.
Shooty Outlanders work well with anything when it comes to armors, but using parts of a set that gives manasteal never hurts, as Rune Vault is a fairly good skill for manasteal purposes.

Mainhand and Offhand
Mainhand is the most important part of the build, as it offers the base damage of skills and most skills convey it's effects. It's often the best to choose a shotgonne over other weapons, but spelltrigger builds have a higher damage output using a dualwield setup.
This time I'll offer you two-handed weapons and weapon combinations, instead of mainhands and offhands separetely.
Tri-Force Catalyst
Spelltrigger weapon. It's one of the best shotgonnes in the game, as it offers high DPS in the form of purely elemental damage and 5% chance to trigger Glacial Spike, Thunder and Firestorm.
On the other hand, it has an annoying downside, having a 5% chance to cast Chaotic Rift.
Socket it with 3x Eye of Aleera to trigger Glacial Spike!
Bloom's Margin
Physical weapon. While Tri-Force Catalyst is superior in terms of weapon speed and potential DPS, the Bloom's Margin offers a nice chance to immobilize without the annyoing Chaotic Rift proc.
Obviously, stuff 3x Vellinque Skulls into it for even moar physical damage!
Netherrealm Shotgonne
Spelltrigger and damage over time weapon. While it's damage is purely physical, it's 5% chance to proc Thunder and it's 5 open sockets make for a great shotgonne used in spelltrigger builds. Also, the 5 open sockets make it ideal for stacking physical damage over time in it.
Socket this one with 5x Eye of Aleera for triggering Glacial Spike or 5x Zardon's Mighty Skull to stack physical damage over time!
Any Pistol & Hammer of Retribution
Spelltrigger weapon combo. Well, if you're ready to sacrifice a guaranteed blind for more chance to trigger spells, get a Hammer of Retribution as offhand and use Ator the Fighting Eagle or Netherrealm Pistol. Ator the fighting Eagle makes up for losing the chance to blind that shotgonnes offer with Shotgonne Mastery, but it's impossibly rare.
Socket both weapon with as much Eye of Aleera as you can stuff into it to increase your chance to trigger Glacial Spike!

Shield
No shields, but if you really-really want to use one, well, it's up to you!
In this case, anything that blocks can work, but I personally recommend Parma's Coal-Burner with it's whopping 45% chance to block, that way you require ~100 vitality only to reach block cap.

Armor
Shooty Outlanders are good with any combination of gear as long as it gives some useful bonuses. While they have no real need for manasteal, it can help to use at least two items from the Liberation or Inquisitor sets or three items of the Aristocrat set.
Your best bet in armor, sockets and enchants is to get the following attributes:
Damage Reduction up to 75% for additional defense.
Chance to reflect missiles.
Strength and Focus, the more the better.
+X Health.
+X% Health.
Casting Speed.
Attack Speed.
Magic finding luck for loot.
Gold finding luck for farming money faster.
Enchant your gear with attributes by Boris, try to get ~150 stat on everything, so that you can hit 1000 strength, ~300+ dexterity and 1000+ focus.
Tactics
General Tactics
Correctly built Shooty Outlanders are so easy to play, that I wonder how they never managed to become a popular cookie-cutter.

Generally, whenever you see something, it's very likely that you can solve the problem with shooting. Rapid Fire mid ranges, Chaos Burst at short ranges, Venomous Hail if the target is large or you have no line of sight to shoot directly at it. Shotgonne Mastery is the trick, whatever you manage to hit, it won't strike back again.
If you have Poison Burst, large crowds of weaker enemies are very likely to die instantly from the first explosion.

Repulsion Hex is an important tool against fast melee enemies, try to cast it whenever the cooldown resets, so to have it on yourself always. Repulsion Hex ensures that you can ignore melee enemies, while you concentrate on killing the ranged and spellcaster ones.

Against ranged and spellcaster enemies, sometimes you have to dodge their missiles, use Rune Vault once or twice.

Bramble Wall and Stone Pact are your friends if you have to kill something that has a larger range than your skills.

Boss Tactics
Well, from all the builds I tried - and I tried a lot -, Shooty Outlander is the most effective at killing bosses. Once you shoot it, the boss becomes blinded, and you have no additional problems.

While bosses have ~90% resistance to stuns and ~80% resistances to immobilization effects, their resist to blind effects is exteremely low, 70% in most cases. If you strike first, they will never strike back.
Hardcore
Hardcore in Singleplayer
Well, every build for hadcore needs to meet some important requirements. Also, it's important to meet most of these early, especially in elite.
Strong offense
Effective crowd control
Swift mobility
Heavy defense

Strong offense - check
At the start of the game, Rapid Fire is already unlocked, not much later, Chaos Burst is accessible as well, both skills do considerable weapon DPS to multiple targets. All these skills along with Venomous Hail scale well endgame.

Effective crowd control - check
Early on, Shotgonne Mastery is accessible and it gives a very powerful crowd control to every weapon attack. Attacks with multiple projectiles that can convey Shotgonne Mastery are also accessible early in the game.

Swift mobility - check
Rune Vault is accessible early and it serves well as a mobility skill. While it works differently than other skills, you jump in the opposite direction your character faces, so you can instantly use it without moving your mouse in combat. Well, with practice it's fine, otherwise you'll fail.

Heavy defense - error
Well, defense is something that only engineers have in this game, so don't take it badly. At least you're ranged, not like the poor berserkers who fight in melee with the same zero defense!

Hardcore in Multiplayer
Hardcore is something you should play in coop if you can. Of course, stay away from unknown people, strangers, aliens, extraterrestrials and cheaters. Back to the topic, every well-built dedicated hardcore coop party has two important roles:
Support - yeah, that's the Force Field spamming Engineer...
Crowd Control - yeah, a shooty outlander, hey, that's you!
Guess what! One of these ensures that the party survives a strike now and then, the other one ensures, that noone will strike twice.

If you plan to play hardcore coop and one of your friends already plays an engineer, then go pick the Shooty Outlander!

You can stop bosses from instagibbing your friends. Is that not cool enough for you? While you shoot a boss, the others can stop running around in panic and concentrate on killing stuff instead of dodging like mad!
Shotgonne Mastery saves time and energy for the whole party! Shotgonne Mastery to the rescue! And so once again the day is saved thanks to the powerpuff girls Shooty Outlander!
Epilogue
Author's Epilogue
Well, this one is quite easy, isn't it? My favourite outlander build, but I have so much more! On the other hand, none of my other builds can decimate bosses as fast and easily as the Shooty Outlander can.

Well, my first shotty outlander, Ashoora was a shooty/summon build, it was quite good actually, but I wanted even more out of her! After some tweaking, I decided to convert her to a shooty build with more support skills, but I was too lazy to level her. After that, I learned about spelltriggers and stuff and I decided that it's cool enough for her and that's all.

Okay, she's a lot less effective without gear than my Emberquaker, but she's still much stronger than my glaivelander.

Have fun and if you liked this, stay tuned for more!
< >
99 Comments Subscribe to thread (?)

Add a comment
Formatting help
    
Post Comment

neustar 4 Jul @ 3:05am 
Possibly the most broken build ever. For years i thought that every boss in the game was absolutely imune to blindness.

Decepticide 30 Jun, 2021 @ 1:07pm 
Thank you! ❤

75338 27 Apr, 2021 @ 5:20am 
Master of the Elements yay or nay?

lis_baka 21 Feb, 2021 @ 8:54pm 
Hey, if anyone alive in here, can u explane a thing to newbee? Author mentioning some "speltrigger" and "DoT" builds, obviously, based on this guide. I wonder, what is the difference? I guess, speltrigger build main idea is to use maxed Poisin Burst, but wtf is DoT build prefer? Sorry if looks stupid, but need answer on this///

Metalhead1652 26 Sep, 2020 @ 1:24pm 
interesting thinking but completely flawed dynamic; outlander with low dodge on hardcore elite is gonna die very quickly

there's points in the game where the enemy goes zerg on your character and I promise you, that's when you die the fastest

Sergeant Poultry 17 Jul, 2020 @ 12:20am 
Lmao first time playing shooty outlander and I put the majority of my points into Akimbo, Long range mastery and dodge mastery. Oops.

Rainover68/Purganis 7 Mar, 2020 @ 10:28am 
Hi friend started play torchlight recently thanks for the guide! How much vitality do i need? Im playing HC on the hardest dificulty!

Agathodaemon 13 Nov, 2019 @ 10:38pm 
How can I get 1000 str? Enchants?

JewelryStar 17 Oct, 2019 @ 4:13pm 
/txhuy88

@Nihilninja: if you want to play with DoT Outlander build, you can go with Shotgone and using max Shotgone passive skill, it can help you "play" with even bosses, Venomous Hail can stacked alot Conveys dmg on target in VH's landed area. And yes, you can spend all attribute points into Focus to boost Conveys dmg, Dex just enough to wearing gears. You can play focus all on DoT/Conveys dmg or mix both of them, or full crit dmg (which you combine Dex enough to wearing gears and +%crit chance from gears to good enough %crit, then the rest attribute points focus on Str).

Revan 11 Apr, 2019 @ 8:26am 
@kardfogu if i go with the dot build should i go all focus enchants and focus gems in gear? (after enough dex to equip the endgame outlander set. Im going with a mix of Dominion and unearthly) . OR should I go for max crit damage for some extra damage while applying my DOTs
< >

Beginning to feel a lot like Mailbag

Beginning to feel a lot like Mailbag

Matthew Yglesias — Read time: 19 minutes


Beginning to feel a lot like Mailbag

Long movies, dysfunctional agencies, and the case for incumbency advantage


At the suggestion of Matthew Edwards in the comments of “Secret Congress delivers more good news on clean water,” I’m going to try to routinely include some positive developments at the top of these mailbag columns.


The obvious one this week, I think, is the inclusion of the Electoral Count Act in the omnibus appropriations bill. The ECA will help forestall efforts to steal future presidential elections, which is good on its own terms. But more broadly, its inclusion represents implicit recognition on the part of GOP leadership that what Trump did at the end of his presidency was really bad in ways that transcend partisan politics. And I think that’s worth noting not because the ECA solves every problem, but because I think its passage does cut against certain widely-made, super-pessimistic forecasts that I haven’t really seen people revisit, even though it’s been looking likely that this would happen for a while now.


I’m also glad to see governor-elect Maura Healy talking about the need for land use reform in Massachusetts.


Now, on to the mailbag!


Marie Kennedy: Not sure if you caught Michelle Goldberg highlighting a piece by Maurice Mitchell as an antidote to the Tema Okun problem... What’s the word on the street in DC? Is “the fever breaking” in leftist political organizations, or is it just wishful thinking on Goldberg’s part?


It’s a great piece column from Goldberg and a great piece from Mitchell and I’m glad they wrote them. Is it wishful thinking? I wouldn’t put it that way. I think that if you could read Goldberg’s mind, she would say that institutional dysfunction is in part self-sustaining because if people think other people are terrified, they will be terrified themselves. Part of causing the fever to break is to tell other people that the fever has broken and they will be safe if they respond in a sensible way to controversies that arise.


My broad sense is that she is right, and the fever is breaking.


That said, my word of caution continues to be that progressive groups are inherently vulnerable to meltdowns as long as they don’t meet their own standards for diversity, and those standards may be unrealistic unless people can go back to addressing talent pipeline issues as legitimate concerns.


Mike: I was pleasantly surprised that you liked Jeanne Dielman, because you've seemed to have very “dadcore” movie tastes. And now I see you watching Claire Denis movies and also liking them. Newfound appreciation for arthouse cinema, or have you always secretly liked this kind of thing? And bonus question: Is it good for the S&S list to be headed by an excellent movie that most people haven't heard of and will probably hate, or would it be better for it to stick to safe popular classics?


I spent a lot of time seeing arthouse movies in the mid-aughts when I had tons of time on my hands and friends who liked to do that sort of thing. I drifted away from it over the years and I do fundamentally have a poppier sensibility than the “Sight and Sound” poll. If you ask me my favorite movies, the answers just aren’t going to be old foreign films. That said, the latest poll jolted me out of my dogmatic slumber and got me to finally sign up for Criterion Channel, and I’ve seen a bunch of great things there.


In terms of “Jeanne Dielman” at the top of the list, it’s not a choice that I love from the standpoint of what’s good for cinema’s role in culture.


I think it’s not just an arty movie but almost an academic one — you need to be pretty steeped in movies to appreciate a film that’s largely playing with our expectations of what a movie should be like. Now by that token, I can see why a distinguished panel of film critics would like it — they’ve seen a ton of movies. But what I liked about the AFI “100 Greatest American Movies of All Time” list is that I think it makes for a good homework assignment for someone who’s decided they like movies and want to learn more about movies and film history. You can quibble with the picks and it has terrible representation of Black and female filmmakers, but in broad strokes, this is an introduction to some of the best-executed versions of mainstream filmmaking and serves a clear pedagogical purpose.


That’s not really a criticism of S&S to be clear, but I think a survey of critics’ tastes is just less interesting than a more deliberately curatorial exercise.


George: I’ve read a lot of commentary handwringing movies being too long (think the 2.5-3+ hour runtimes of movies this year like “The Batman,” “Wakanda Forever,” “The Fabelmans,” “Avatar 2,” and the upcoming “Babylon”.) As a guy who likes movies, do you have any thoughts to contribute on this discourse?


I am not a fan of the long movie trend. I think it is defensible if you are adapting a novel to sometimes say “look, the novel was written to be a novel, not to be a movie, so I was forced to choose between the compromise of an inappropriately long film or compromising on the story, and I decided all things considered that the best thing to do was to go long.” I will also accept, as in the aforementioned Jeanne Dielman, that sometimes being long is part of the point.


But in general, the nature of the medium is that it should be short. James Cameron said that if you can binge-watch a TV show you can watch a long movie and that it’s fine to just get up and go pee. But I disagree with that. Part of what makes a TV show not just a very long movie is that it has breaks built into it. You should be able to sit down in a movie theater with a soda, drink the soda, and then go pee after the movie is over. And part of the job of the screenwriter, the director, and the editor is to compose a story that fits those parameters. You’re sitting down to make a Batman reboot and you could write basically anything — go write something that’s the length of a proper movie! Raiders of the Lost Ark is 115 minutes, E.T. is 114 minutes — the whole reason we might care about Steven Spielberg’s thinly veiled autobiography is that he’s a master filmmaker. He knows what length a movie should be. Go make a movie that length.


I rewatched the 80-minute “Run Lola Run” recently. Part of its brilliance is that Tom Tykwer and his editor Mathilde Bonnefoy pack a ton of information into this frame. You learn all about Lola’s family, the creepy bank security guard, Manni’s life of crime, and the whole possible future life trajectories of several other residents of Berlin all in the context of a gripping, suspenseful movie that is also short. This isn’t easy, but that’s the job.


Claire: Obviously, your (Matt’s) relationship with Effective Altruism has always been a bit uneasy, and that’s even more true now post-FTX implosion. You’ve mentioned before that the optics of Effective Altruism were never particularly good (it’s largely a group of nerds sitting around in T-shirts, and not a group you can easily introduce to policy makers), and I think we can all agree that the SBF has at least temporarily made EA politically toxic.


If you were going to deliver advice to individuals in EA leadership roles, what would you personally recommend on how to make these ideas less politically toxic over the next several years?


(Disclosure: I work for an EA-aligned organization, but not in a communications or external-facing role.)


One baseline observation is that the large amount of money FTX was pumping into the movement created gravitational incentives toward being inward-looking. There was a sense of an abundance of money but scarcity of attention, so the key first-order priority to was to persuade other EAs that your thing was important on EA terms so that you could elevate it on the EA agenda.


This post I wrote making the case for more funding of alternative protein research came about because of a conversation Kate had with Bruce Friedrich of the Good Food Institute at the EA Global conference in D.C. And in official EA doctrinal terms, the case for alternative protein research is mostly about animal welfare. But my post is mostly about climate change, because climate is a more mainstream policy issue, climate philanthropy is a lot larger than EA, and “negative environmental externalities associated with farming should be reduced when possible” is a lot less philosophically contentious than animal welfare. It’s a completely above-board pitch — the climate impact of agriculture is genuinely large, and we have thus far made almost no progress on addressing it. But it’s also an effort to spend less time in an internal argument about cause prioritization and more time just bringing an EA perspective to bear on a conversation that’s very mainstream in policy circles.


By the same token, I liked this Scott Alexander post about ChatGPT and racism. Instead of refighting the “x-risk versus algorithmic bias” wars, he’s pointing out that a lot of people are already worried about algorithmic bias and already doing stories about how the anti-bias measures at OpenAI don’t work, so maybe let’s have a broader conversation about the reality that the frontier AI companies keep releasing products that are both incredibly impressive and also fail their own stated goals. The norm in the software industry is that it’s fine to release buggy products and then fix them. But the FAA won’t let you iteratively design passenger airplanes on that basis.


James B: You've written before about the phenomenon of “unrepresentative activists” who claim to speak for minority communities, and how this has played out with respect to the Black, Latino and Asian communities. Do you have a read on whether this same phenomenon is playing out with Native Americans? I have notice a lot of indigenous activists promoting (or being used by progressives to promote) various lefty ideas, some of which feel uncomfortably close to the old “noble savage” trope. Most recently it was a TED Talk about “Indigenous Guardians” protecting the planet from climate change.


There is absolutely some of this going around, but the difference is that Native American nations have formal governance institutions that involve accountability to constituents. So if you want to know what the Navajo Nation wants with regard to some controversy in Arizona or New Mexico politics, there is an actual Navajo Nation President whose job is (among other things) to advocate for Navajo interests. This isn’t to say there’s uniformity or monolithic opinion — the incumbent president lost his reelection bid last fall — but that’s exactly the point. Tribal officials have to actually worry about how representative their ideas are.


Peter Gerdes: What's going on with the NRC? Are the political appointees secretly trying to scuttle nuclear power? I can't imagine that the physicists, nuclear engineers and environmental scientists are attitudinally against more nuclear power.


Is the problem a failure to apply cost/benefit analysis, eg, each concern about a possible risk gets a rule to fix it regardless of the complexity cost? Is it an incentives problem (no one wants to be blamed if things go wrong)?


I wrote about this for Bloomberg recently, but I think the basic model with the career staff of any federal agency is that they basically don’t want things to change. In part because people impatient for change tend to select out of a career in the civil service, but in part because they live in fear of being hung out to dry. There are not, right now, members of Congress yelling at NRC officials about why they aren’t licensing more reactors, and there are no protests at their office. If they do something different, there might be protests and they might get yelled at.


I don’t think of the political appointees as “secretly trying to scuttle nuclear power,” but they also haven’t made a definitive choice to advance nuclear power. And this really becomes a question for Joe Biden, Mitch McConnell, and other congressional leaders. Do they want the NRC commissioners to prod the career staff, even if that results in some articles in the Washington Post about how NRC career staff are worried about prodding from the political appointees? If the NRC does issue new rules and people do start building a new generation of nuclear plants — will the top politicians face down protestors and complainers and tell them they are wrong?


Joseph Politano: What economic event/outcome since the start of the pandemic most surprised you, and how much (if at all) has it shifted how you think about the economy?


I was surprised when the original durable goods inflation took off. Like a lot of things, it’s easy to explain this in retrospect — people had extra money from relief programs and didn’t want to spend it on travel or dining out, so they bought tons of durable goods and that sent prices soaring. But at the time, I thought prices would go up a little bit but then pretty quickly people would say “fuck no, I’m not paying that” and just sit on excess savings. After all, durable goods prices had been in structural decline for a generation or two, and I thought sticker shock would nip inflation in the bud.


Taylor: What’s the case for a young person to become a journalist today? The pay is low, the layoffs are frequent, people blame “the media” for all kinds of bullshit and you’re limited to living in one of two cities, more or less. If you’ve got the skills to be a good journalist, there are many jobs you’ll be good at where you’ll make more money and have better job security. Why bother?


I don’t really encourage people to pursue careers in journalism, but I do want to complicate “the pay is low” as an idea. What’s happened is that journalism has become more of a star-driven, hits-driven, tournament-like business. Thanks to the internet, it’s possible to reach more people than ever before and to monetize in a bigger variety of ways. So the pay has become more unequal, which has made it a riskier undertaking but not necessarily a worse one, depending on your appetite for that kind of thing.


kjz: Tyler Cowen recently wrote a short post about his disillusionment with the Westminster system of government. The main thrust of his criticism is that UK politics is even more gridlocked than American politics, despite the centralization of executive power. Given that you've previously written favorably of the Westminster system (which Tyler mentions in his post), does this argument resonate with you? Why or why not?


The main thing I think about U.K. politics is that their land use policy is very bad and also a much bigger deal than comparable land use issues in the United States thanks to the different geography of the country. I don’t see that problem as stemming from either parliamentarianism or centralization, which are the two main aspects of the British constitutional order that Cowen criticizes.


I’d also say that a lot of recent problems in British politics have their origins at least in part in key actors abandoning the logic of Westminster-style constitutionalism. That’s Nick Clegg joining a coalition rather than letting David Cameron helm a weak minority government, it’s Cameron holding a Brexit referendum rather than upholding parliamentary sovereignty, and it’s both Labour and the Tories making big policy pivots based on American-style leadership primaries rather than closed-door meetings of MPs.


Greg S: Is the fact of incumbency advantage good? Should we want to see it shrink or grow?


Here are two things I want from the political system:


Voters should be responsive to what politicians actually do in office.


Politicians should be responsive to what their constituents want.


If both of those things hold, most incumbents will cater to local interests and voters will notice that, and the result will be that incumbents outperform on average. So I think a healthy incumbency advantage is probably a sign of a healthy political system. But that’s not because incumbency advantage is per se good.


David: Are there any issues where you felt very strongly before you found some data that reversed your position?


It’s pretty rare to see some data and then suddenly change your mind. But there are lots of things where my opinion has shifted over time as I’ve learned more — one is about transportation infrastructure, where back 10-15 years ago I would have adhered to a very conventional “just spend more money” line. My land use views have evolved over time from “we need to foster quality urbanism” to “we just need to allow more housing.” And I think my health care views have shifted to more emphasis on health insurance as financial insurance to protect people against the economic consequences of ill health and less as a central lever of public health policy.


Walker: Who would be the best plausible nominee for Dems in the 2024 Presidential Election? I think it would be Whitmer.


In the real world, the best thing for Democrats is for Biden to run again.


If you could avoid a primary and just install a different person by acclamation, then yeah, I think Gretchen Whitmer looks like a very strong choice. You could maybe balance the ticket with Ben Ray Luján.


But realistically, it remains the case that the odds are very good that the next time Biden is not the nominee it’s going to be Kamala Harris, and the best thing for Democrats is for Harris to make better political decisions. I feel like I end up saying this every other mailbag, but she should be spending time with Whitmer and her team (and Catherine Cortez Masto and Tammy Baldwin and Roy Cooper) and building out a circle of people who are experienced with winning in purple and red states. Harris’ only genuine weakness in a potential primary is that people are worried she’ll lose. If she has a laser focus on being popular and winning, she’ll easily brush off leftist opposition. But right now, almost nobody is convinced she’s a general election winner.


Michael Adelman: How do you rate the chances of Ron DeSantis becoming an American Orbán and achieving a decades-long hammerlock on power for the GOP? David Shor considers DeSantis a heavy favorite to win the 2024 election with a massive Senate majority. And DeSantis has shown many Orbán-like tendencies - aggressively entrenching partisan advantages, wielding state power against civil society in illiberal ways, rallying support with anti-immigrant and anti-LGBTQ culture war, etc. I could easily imagine a world where DeSantis and the state/Federal officials that ride his coattails grow the GOP's structural advantages by a few more points, after which it starts to feel hopeless to oppose them especially in a country where self-described liberals are a tiny minority. As a supporter of social programs, environmental policy, and pluralism, this makes me really sad, but I fear the odds of DeSantis both winning and locking in GOP power are pretty high. Do you agree? And what (if anything) should liberals be doing now to avoid the fate of the Hungarian opposition?


I don’t find it that constructive to dwell on exactly how likely I think worst-case scenarios are.


The main thing I would say about DeSantis is that given the 2024 map, he could easily take the White House and a large Senate majority with 50 percent or even 49 percent of the two-party vote. And DeSantis plus a large Senate majority would likely enact large cuts in Medicaid and other anti-poverty programs and at least attempt the kind of big cuts in Medicare that he voted for as a House member. We now also see that he’s come out for a near-total ban on abortions in Florida. To me, those are sufficient reasons to not vote for him, and I think that if most Americans believe a DeSantis administration would mean cutting Medicare and Medicaid while banning abortion, they won’t vote for him either.


So unless he radically pivots away from his House record on these issues, the idea I am going to try to keep front and center is that Ron DeSantis has bad positions on major public policy issues.


Philip R: Me and my fiancee are moving to DC soon and want to live inside the city - what neighborhoods would you recommend for a young YIMBY couple with a basset hound? Access to parks and the metro would be a major plus.


It’s a little hard to opine without knowing the details of your situation, but my general advice would be to look in the string of neighborhoods that follow the Green Line north from downtown — Shaw, U Street, Columbia Heights, Petworth — that all offer good city living and transit access, but also plenty of opportunities to have a small yard for the dog.


David_in_Chicago: Why can't successful CEOs find successful replacements (e.g., Iger, Dalio, Bezos, Schultz)? Does the shadow loom too large? Does the replacement's need to insert their ideas create disruption?


It’s not like this never happens — both Apple and Google have had successful leadership transitions, and I don’t think it’s clear that your pessimism about Amazon is entirely correct.


But my guess is the main reason that these transitions sometimes go badly is that it’s objectively hard and also not necessarily something any given CEO has experience with. There’s not some obvious way to practice. What’s interesting is that when a successful transition does happen, it often constitutes big change. Tim Cook has been a successful CEO, but he’s nothing like Steve Jobs. He is instead a guy who rose to a senior leadership role at Apple by having skills that were highly complementary to Jobs’ skills, which meant that he was already running large swathes of the company before taking over. But that in turn meant that while Cook is now the CEO instead of Jobs, it would be misleading to say that Cook does the work that Jobs used to do — the whole way responsibilities are parceled out is completely different.


Michael Tolhurst: If part of good policy is priming the culture, I'm curious what a Slow Boring holiday Hallmark movie might look.


Is it a high powered executive director of a DC progressive non profit returning to her hometown and falling in love with a staffer for a congressman from a suburban district outside of Cleveland? Or does the couple find love after feuding over the future of a now defunct historic holiday theme park that is planned to be redeveloped into [a new mass transit station/high density housing/large scale renewable]? What would be the key themes of such a movie, and how could the genre be adapted to best express the themes of the blog?


A greedy real estate developer, a woke community activist, and a normie homeowner end up snowed in together with some construction workers and sales agents and need to piece together an improved holiday celebration for themselves. By actually talking to each other in a real and direct way, they discover that their interests, though not identical, are reconcilable once they recognize that reducing deadweight loss generates surplus.


Russell Brandom: Do you have a favored remedy for reforming a broken institution? What should we do when an important agency is no longer capable of fulfilling its function? Lots of the discourse (both right and left) seems to be grappling with some version of this, but I have not heard a general theory of how to respond to institutional failure.


I think shutting agencies down and spinning up new ones is underrated. One of the real successes of the Dodd-Frank financial reform law was creating a brand-new Consumer Financial Protection Bureau with a distinct ethos and esprit de corps. They also shut down the dysfunctional Office of Thrift Supervision and parceled out its functions to other regulatory agencies.


Another example is the police reform saga of Camden, New Jersey, which didn’t “defund the police” but did literally eliminate the city’s police department and replace it with policing services they contracted from the county. Many of the officers in the “new” department were just the people who’d worked at the old department, but the point was that the new department was new and everyone had to apply for their jobs. I have a friend who ran a school turnaround project where, similarly, a failing high school was shut down and then a “new” high school was established in the same building. She ended up hiring a lot of the “old” high school’s former employees but not all of them — and it was a fresh start with not just a new principal and some new staff, but a new tone and a new culture.


Update your profile

Only paid subscribers can comment on this post

Check your email

For your security, we need to re-authenticate you.


Click the link we sent to tka.lee@gmail.com, or click here to sign in.